Monday, December 22, 2014

Economics of Brand Names



Professor Boudreaux's thoughts on brand names and health:

I’m sure that somewhere someone has tried to document or to measure the contribution to food safety of brand names (and other private quality-assurance methods) relative to the contribution of government regulation, such as that supplied in the U.S. by inspectors for the U.S.D.A. and various state and local bureaucrats.  But I’m unfamiliar with any such studies.  My strong prior is that the contribution of brand names and other private-sector institutions far outstrips that of government regulation.

More from the post:
Brand names are one of the many ways that markets supply public goods – solve free-rider problems – internalize externalities.  If, say, dairies all sold milk in homogeneous containers, then Jones the dairy farmer would have less incentive to incur costs to improve or to maintain the quality of his milk: because his milk is indistinguishable, in consumers’  eyes, from other-producers’ milk, Jones personally pockets all the money he saves by not spending it on quality enhancement and assurance, while the costs of his actions are spread out among countless consumers and other dairy farmers.  The reason is that Jones’s low-quality milk reduces the average quality of the milk supply available to consumers, so consumers’ demand for milk falls from what it would have been were the quality of milk higher.  All dairy farmers suffer from the lower price they get for their milk.
Of course, what’s true for farmer Jones is true for all other dairy farmers.  All dairy farmers have incentives to skimp on quality.  So milk’s quality is kept low.
But now comes farmer Smith who markets his milk in branded packages with a unique design, logo, color scheme, and slogan (“Smith’s – The Yummiest Milk!”).  If Smith acts as Jones does, Smith suffers more than Jones does.  Smith would, like farmer Jones, pocket all the money saved by scrimping on maintaining his milk’s quality, but unlike Jones, Smith would also suffer the full consequence of his scrimping on quality.  Consumers, tasting Smith’s poor-quality milk and being able to identify it as coming from Smith’s farm, would reduce their demands for Smith’s milk and increase their demands for milk other than Smith’s.  Therefore, Smith has much less incentive than does Jones to supply poor-quality milk.  Smith’s branding keeps Smith honest.  And Smith himself has the incentive to devise and use this means of keeping himself honest.  No top-down command from government officials was necessary.

No comments:

Post a Comment